|
META TOPICPARENT | name="FirstPaper" |
The Drug Prisoner’s Dilemma
-- By AlexKonik - 02 Jun 2012 |
|
< < | Drugs are big business. The legal kinds generate billions of dollars in revenue for companies clearing the next big clogged artery. The illegal kinds implicate just as much money, but the interested parties are more diverse. Illegal suppliers enjoy inflated prices from governmental supply suppression; police departments enjoy inflated budgets to combat the criminalized activity; prison contractors enjoy unprecedented prison populations that are increasingly confined, fed, and otherwise handled by private industry; citizens enjoy gainful employment through the confining business; politicians retain their offices by cleaning up the streets and being tough on crime; and recreational drug users retain their access under a porous enforcement scheme that keeps drugs eminently available. |
> > | |
| |
|
< < | Although recent state moves considering limited medical use of marijuana hint at a new direction, Drugs continue to inhabit a forbidden place in American society. A policy of looser heroine punishment in favor of more treatment resources will lose if it is based on sound principles of economics or historical lessons. The War On Drugs will not end with a reasoned debate. |
> > | The Prisoner’s Dilemma illustrates both the great potential and likely pitfall of some collective action. Two men are charged with a crime. Each must choose whether to implicate his partner in a bargain with the police or remain steadfast and trust that his partner will do the same. The total punishment is least when both criminals remain silent and force the police to trial. American drug criminals face an analogous choice. Possibly the most effective way of reducing punishment for drug offenses is through coordination of prisoners, by refusing pleas for any punishment more severe than treatment. Like any coordination problem, there are obstacles to success. Prisoner’s Dilemma is deceiving because there is no dilemma; each knows that the other will plea because it always results in a lesser punishment for the individual. |
| |
|
< < | There may be a bottleneck in the War On Drugs’ support loop, and necessity could be decisive where habit and social mores only perpetuate the status quo. The kink may be in prosecutorial and court resources. While a long list of parties benefit from the War, prosecutors and courts bear a substantial cost burden. Unlike prisons and police, increased funding to these administrative departments are unattractive, invisible to the public, and taste more of bureaucracy than justice. The lobbying interest in expanding judicial appointments and DA budgets is less focused than the prison lobby and commands less force than the public’s concern with safety. In comparison, at least, this public function sees the most cost and least gain from the War. |
> > | Some Are Winning the War On Drugs |
| |
|
< < | Facing tough budgets and short time, the adjudication of an ever-expanding volume of drug cases survives on plea bargains. Virtually no one goes to trial; this is by design. Facing limited resources, prosecutors must prioritize the cases they bring and forecast the resources they demand. A trial will be a much larger investment than a plea, but one hopes that the expected cost is balanced with the severity of the crime. With the huge volume of the docket that relatively minor drugs crimes occupy, there exists real potential to exacerbate this adjudication bottleneck of the War. Drug criminals, acting in concert, could put serious pressure on current enforcement policies by refusing to accept pleas that carry conditions other than treatment. By bringing every question to a jury that faces a stiffer plea than treatment, drug criminals will fundamentally change the equation prosecutors face when deciding who and how to prosecute. Where the political recourse is destined to fail, collective action can succeed in changing practiced policy. |
> > | Drugs are big business. Illegal suppliers enjoy inflated prices from governmental supply suppression; police departments enjoy inflated budgets to combat the criminalized activity; prison contractors enjoy unprecedented prison populations that are increasingly confined, fed, and otherwise handled by private industry; citizens enjoy gainful employment through the confining business; politicians retain their offices by cleaning up the streets and being tough on crime; and recreational drug users retain their access under a porous enforcement scheme that keeps drugs eminently available. Although recent state moves considering medical marijuana hint at a new direction, drugs continue to inhabit a forbidden place in American society. With public opinion mirroring the view of the parties who profit, a policy of looser heroine punishment in favor of more treatment resources would stand little chance of being proposed or approved. Because of this, the War On Drugs likely will not end with a de jure, legislative measure. |
| |
|
< < | The mass incarceration of drug offenders is successful today only because the victims are coerced into helping the system function. Not only the judge and jailor, but the prisoner and his lawyer grease the cogs of the very machine that imprisons him. In one respect at least, the indicted masses are in a position of power. Though today, through individual acquiescence, they abandon their power in a way that Thoreau feared: “a minority is powerless while it conforms to the majority; it is not even a minority then; but it is irresistible when it clogs by its whole weight.” Like he and Mario Savio called for in other contexts, real change is possible if you “put your bodies upon the gears and upon the wheels, upon the levers, upon all the apparatus, and you've got to make it stop. And you've got to indicate to the people who run it, to the people who own it, that unless you're free, the machine will be prevented from working at all." |
> > | The Courts Are Losing |
| |
|
< < | Given the number of those charged with drug crimes, the tremendous weight burdening the criminal system already today, the enormous difference in cost between a plea and a trial, and the potential to bring even more claims demanding a speedy trial as the docket continues to backlog, prosecutors will have little choice as the gears of the machine clog. If prosecutorial discretion does not de facto institute a policy change to treatment as punishment to drug crimes, a legislative response loosening punishment may be forced. |
> > | However there may be a bottleneck in the War On Drugs’ support loop. While a long list of parties benefit from the War, prosecutors and courts bear a substantial cost burden and see few of its benefits. Unlike prisons and police, increased funding to these administrative departments is unattractive, invisible to the public, and tastes more of bureaucracy than justice. The lobbying interest in expanding judicial resources and DA budgets is less focused than the prison lobby and wields less influence than the public’s concern with safety. The War is leaving courts overstrained and underfunded. |
| |
|
< < | There is, of course, the very large hurdle of achieving collective action. The story of oppression is so often one of preventing coordinated action. Slavery in the United States was helped by criminalizing education, and legally retarding collective bargaining helped in class conflicts. When benefits of action are not realized until a critical mass is reached, early actors are punished severely. |
> > | The Courts Have a Weakness |
| |
|
< < | Victories have come through collective action where, as here, individual incentives made predicting success dubious. Martin Luther King, Jr. led a civil rights movement where many were individually harmed beyond the benefit they could expect to personally enjoy. The NAACP Legal Defense and Education Fund orchestrated a coordinated plan of targeted litigation that has proved a successful model for other impact litigation causes since. Ideally, a coordinated group makes decisions that are best for cause; some individual grievances may be sacrificed to advance the cause, hopefully with few defections. |
> > | Facing tough budgets and short time, the adjudication of an ever-expanding volume of drug cases survives on plea bargains. Virtually no one goes to trial and the system has come to rely on this. Facing limited resources, prosecutors must prioritize the cases they bring to court, and a trial costs much more than a plea. With the huge volume of the docket that relatively minor drugs crimes occupy, there exists real potential to exacerbate this adjudication bottleneck. Drug criminals, acting in concert, could put serious pressure on current enforcement policies by refusing to accept pleas that carry conditions more severe than treatment. By bringing every question to a jury that faces a stiffer plea than treatment, drug criminals will fundamentally change the equation prosecutors face when deciding who and how to prosecute. Where a preferred legislative solution offers little hope of reform, collective action could succeed in changing policy de facto. |
| |
|
< < | The War On Drugs does not contain the same obvious moral defect that abolitionists and civil rights leaders fought against. Although its enforcement is the most recent step in a long history of racial segregation, the social understanding of the underlying criminal activity (using drugs) is less offensive than punishing skin color. |
> > | There Is Strength in Numbers |
| |
|
< < | In this realm of social policy where economic interests align with guiding habit and emotion, we can look for a weakness in the system to force change. The sheer size of the War On Drugs creates its own vulnerability; the system cannot sustain itself if the subjugated put their bodies upon the machine in resistance rather than lubrication. |
> > | The mass incarceration of drug offenders is possible today only because the victims are coerced into helping the system function. Not only the judge and jailor, but the prisoner and his lawyer grease the cogs of the very machine that imprisons him. In one respect at least, the indicted masses are in a position of power. Given the number of those charged with drug crimes, the tremendous weight burdening the judicial system, and the enormous cost of trial, prosecutors will have little choice as the gears of the machine seize. Furthermore, there is potential to bring even more claims demanding a speedy trial as the docket continues to backlog. |
| |
|
> > | Is There A Dilemma?
There are, of course, very large hurdles to achieving collective action. First, even after a critical mass has been reached to sufficiently impact the system, each prisoner would still enjoy a benefit by pleading while the rest cooperate. The terms of pleading will become more favorable as the system groans louder, and each prisoner will face his “dilemma.” Second, although cooperating prisoners can improve their collective fate, early actors are especially prone to severe punishment before a critical mass is reached. Additionally, there are ethical concerns for counsel. Game theory often presents scenarios expecting extra-human rationality, but a lawyer likely cannot advise his client to take actions that will knowingly enhance his sentence. One lawyer may be able to represent a sufficient number of clients to overcome the Prisoner’s Dilemma by acting as a single decision maker. He could promote the group’s collective interest rather than fall prey to individual incentives. With confidence in this lawyer, prisoners may decide to transcend their dilemma.
Conclusion
In this realm of social policy where economic interests align with public opinion and habit, we can look for a weakness in the system to force change. The sheer size of the War On Drugs creates its own vulnerability; the system cannot sustain itself if the subjugated act in resistance rather than facilitation. With a sufficient number of drug criminals forcing trial, two outcomes are likely: either prosecutorial discretion will de facto institute a policy change favoring treatment over punishment, or a de jure legislative response will be forced. |
| |
|
< < | (I remain interested in working on the paper and topic) |
| |
|
< < | -- AlexKonik - 14 Feb 2012 |
> > | “A minority is powerless while it conforms to the majority; it is not even a minority then; but it is irresistible when it clogs by its whole weight.” - Thoreau
(I remain interested in working on the paper and topic) |
| |
|
< < | I like your piece, but just a note: I was having a conversation the other day with this girl who's an attorney for the Orleans Public Defenders office and I asked her if she thought plea deals should be abolished. She responded, "I can't deal with that academic BS. My clients are 17-year-old kids who are facing 40 years in prison for possession. Telling them to take their cases to trial is not an option." Your essay acknowledges this fact but doesn't answer it. How are we supposed to tell 17-year-old kids to take their chances at trial? If we can't, isn't this all just academic BS? |
| |
|
< < | -- JaredMiller - 27 Jun 2012 |
| \ No newline at end of file |
|
> > | For all interested, I have invited John McWhorter (Columbia) and Richard Willard (former Assistant Attorney General) to debate about the War On Drugs at CLS. They will be speaking at noon on Thursday, October 18 in JG. |