Law in Contemporary Society

View   r23  >  r22  >  r21  >  r20  >  r19  >  r18  ...
DeathofGiantFirms 23 - 11 Jan 2010 - Main.IanSullivan
Line: 1 to 1
Changed:
<
<
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
>
>
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes2008Jan16"
 The marginal return to transactional work of an investment in legal education will certainly diminish. Ivy-educated lawyers will be only slightly more valuable, and much more costly, than graduates of third-tier schools, lawyers in India, and software.

But lawmaking, unlike transactional work, does not produce value that is easily measured and compared to the costs of production. When litigation creates a precedent, or when the lobbyist or appellant proposes to reform the law, it implicates the very existence of a stream of value for the indefinite future. It rallies powerful opposing interests. It is war by other means. War leads to arms races, and arms races get out of control.

Line: 92 to 92
 -- AdamCarlis - 23 Jan 2008
Changed:
<
<
I respond to Christina by saying two things. First, I agree that there is a branding market out there, and that name of where you went to school can open doors for you, but I agree with Adam that this need not always be so. So the question then becomes, what else (besides go to a top school) can we do to to insulate ourselves in job stability and happiness? I think that Eben hit the nail on the head when he said that the key is to learn to be 'flexible' and to be able to do a variety of different things for different clients. There is a great saying that I think expresses this well: "the more you can do, the more you can do". If the 'death of firms' occurs, the pedigree won't matter as much as what you can do for your clients.
>
>
I respond to Christina by saying two things. First, I agree that there is a branding market out there, and that name of where you went to school can open doors for you, but I agree with Adam that this need not always be so. So the question then becomes, what else (besides go to a top school) can we do to to insulate ourselves in job stability and happiness? I think that Eben hit the nail on the head when he said that the key is to learn to be 'flexible' and to be able to do a variety of different things for different clients. There is a great saying that I think expresses this well: "the more you can do, the more you can do". If the 'death of firms' occurs, the pedigree won't matter as much as what you can do for your clients.
 -- JustinColannino - 23 Jan 2008

DeathofGiantFirms 22 - 27 Jan 2008 - Main.AndrewGradman
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
The marginal return to transactional work of an investment in legal education will certainly diminish. Ivy-educated lawyers will be only slightly more valuable, and much more costly, than graduates of third-tier schools, lawyers in India, and software.
Line: 6 to 6
 In an arms race, "better than the competitor" is all that’s needed. Corporations with immeasurably large interests in changing the law will continue to pay unconscionably large sums to keep their competitors away from the “better” sources of creative legal ideas, even if those ideas are downright bad. Columbia Law School has no incentive to retool its curriculum for the new economy, as long as no other "top tier" law school does.
Changed:
<
<
But other schools will. It's what we comfortably call "second tier" schools--schools whose teachers are practitioners instead of scholars--schools that compete with each other to break their students into firms--that will produce the lawyers that will outstrip us.
>
>
But other schools will. It's what we comfortably call "second tier" schools--schools whose teachers are practitioners instead of scholars--schools that compete with each other to break their students into firms--that will produce the lawyers that will outstrip us.
 -- AndrewGradman - 27 Jan 2008

DeathofGiantFirms 21 - 27 Jan 2008 - Main.AndrewGradman
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
The marginal return to transactional work of an investment in legal education will certainly diminish. Ivy-educated lawyers will be only slightly more valuable, and much more costly, than graduates of third-tier schools, lawyers in India, and software.
Changed:
<
<
But lawmaking by litigation, unlike transactional negotiations, does not produce value that is easily measured and compared to the costs of production. When the case creates a precedent, or when the lobbyist or appellant proposes to reform the law for the indefinite future, it implicates the very existence of a stream of value for the indefinite future. It rallies powerful opposing interests. It is war by other means. War leads to arms races, and arms races get out of control.
>
>
But lawmaking, unlike transactional work, does not produce value that is easily measured and compared to the costs of production. When litigation creates a precedent, or when the lobbyist or appellant proposes to reform the law, it implicates the very existence of a stream of value for the indefinite future. It rallies powerful opposing interests. It is war by other means. War leads to arms races, and arms races get out of control.
 
Changed:
<
<
In an arms race, "better than the competitor" is all that’s needed. Corporations with immeasurably large interests in changing the law will continue to pay unconscionably large sums to keep the “better” sources of creative legal ideas away from their competitors, even if they're downright bad. Columbia Law School has no incentive to educate its students for the new economy, as long as no other "top tier" law school does.
>
>
In an arms race, "better than the competitor" is all that’s needed. Corporations with immeasurably large interests in changing the law will continue to pay unconscionably large sums to keep their competitors away from the “better” sources of creative legal ideas, even if those ideas are downright bad. Columbia Law School has no incentive to retool its curriculum for the new economy, as long as no other "top tier" law school does.
 But other schools will. It's what we comfortably call "second tier" schools--schools whose teachers are practitioners instead of scholars--schools that compete with each other to break their students into firms--that will produce the lawyers that will outstrip us.

DeathofGiantFirms 20 - 27 Jan 2008 - Main.AndrewGradman
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
Deleted:
<
<
What is essential to corporate legal services, and what structure and scale will generate that most efficiently?
 The marginal return to transactional work of an investment in legal education will certainly diminish. Ivy-educated lawyers will be only slightly more valuable, and much more costly, than graduates of third-tier schools, lawyers in India, and software.
Changed:
<
<
But lawmaking by litigation, unlike transactional negotiations, does not produce value that is easily measured and compared to the costs of production. When the litigator’s client is committed to reaching a final verdict, or when the lobbyist or appellant proposes to reform the law for the indefinite future, his mandate is to produce a binary outcome (winning). That outcome implicates the very existence of a stream of value for the indefinite future. It rallies powerful opposing interests. It is war by other means. War leads to arms races, and arms races get out of control.

In an arms race, "better than the competitor" is all that’s needed. Corporations with immeasurably large interests in changing the law will continue to pay unconscionably large sums to keep the “better” sources of creative legal ideas away from their competitors.

>
>
But lawmaking by litigation, unlike transactional negotiations, does not produce value that is easily measured and compared to the costs of production. When the case creates a precedent, or when the lobbyist or appellant proposes to reform the law for the indefinite future, it implicates the very existence of a stream of value for the indefinite future. It rallies powerful opposing interests. It is war by other means. War leads to arms races, and arms races get out of control.
 
Changed:
<
<
Legally educated persons have a monopoly in the production of these ideas, and law schools have a monopoly on creating legally educated persons. Columbia Law School has no incentive to educate its students for the new economy, as long as no other "top tier" law school does.
>
>
In an arms race, "better than the competitor" is all that’s needed. Corporations with immeasurably large interests in changing the law will continue to pay unconscionably large sums to keep the “better” sources of creative legal ideas away from their competitors, even if they're downright bad. Columbia Law School has no incentive to educate its students for the new economy, as long as no other "top tier" law school does.
 
Changed:
<
<
However, other schools will. It's what we comfortably call "second tier" schools--schools whose teachers are practitioners instead of scholars--schools that compete with each other to break their students into firms--that will produce the lawyers that will outstrip us.
>
>
But other schools will. It's what we comfortably call "second tier" schools--schools whose teachers are practitioners instead of scholars--schools that compete with each other to break their students into firms--that will produce the lawyers that will outstrip us.
 
Added:
>
>
-- AndrewGradman - 27 Jan 2008
 -- AndrewGradman - 19 Jan 2008

DeathofGiantFirms 19 - 26 Jan 2008 - Main.AndrewGradman
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
Changed:
<
<

The Death of the Giant Firm?

>
>
What is essential to corporate legal services, and what structure and scale will generate that most efficiently?
 
Changed:
<
<
Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Now that I'm going online to upload this, I just discovered i got a b minus in torts, so take my arguments with a heavy dose of skepticism.
>
>
The marginal return to transactional work of an investment in legal education will certainly diminish. Ivy-educated lawyers will be only slightly more valuable, and much more costly, than graduates of third-tier schools, lawyers in India, and software.
 
Changed:
<
<
Eben believes that giant corporate firms will be extinct by the time we inherit them. I have wondered what could make them obsolete.
>
>
But lawmaking by litigation, unlike transactional negotiations, does not produce value that is easily measured and compared to the costs of production. When the litigator’s client is committed to reaching a final verdict, or when the lobbyist or appellant proposes to reform the law for the indefinite future, his mandate is to produce a binary outcome (winning). That outcome implicates the very existence of a stream of value for the indefinite future. It rallies powerful opposing interests. It is war by other means. War leads to arms races, and arms races get out of control.
 
Changed:
<
<
First, why were they successful? The richest corporations want their legal work mass-produced and custom-fit. Big firms accommodate these clients by exploiting economies of scale. The deep bench supplies apprentices to do drudge work for their mentors, and packing specialists under one roof improves the cross-pollination their ideas, as at interdisciplinary research universities or think tanks.

I believe that Eben believes that the cheap exchange of information will abolish the ownership of symbolic representations: when the “exclusive” right to use becomes unenforceable, the right itself becomes a __. . Then the brokers and networkers of creative thought will become obsolete. Blogs broke the media conglomerate’s monopoly on distributing news. Recording companies will go the way of switchboard operators. Middle Management is being crushed by flattening corporate hierarchies. The continental investment banks ceded power to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies together as second semester seniors.

But creative work will never be socialized, at least until someone invents mind-reading or artificial intelligence. Hedge fund managers will still need intuition to predict capital flow from commercial data; managers will need insight to market and innovate; reporters will always rely on pluck to formulate questions, anticipate the scene of the crime, and research non-symbolic facts; songwriters will always daydream and smoke pot.

So I must rephrase my original question: what is essential to corporate legal services, and what structure and scale will generate that most efficiently?

Some legal products are not valued for being “good,” but for being “better” than the competitor’s. When the litigator’s client is committed to reaching a final verdict, or when the lobbyist or appellant proposes to reform the law for the indefinite future, his mandate is to produce a binary outcome (winning). Legally educated persons have a monopoly in the production of these decisions, because their future creative product is inalienable. The demand for a given litigator will be proportional to his or her relative ability to deny the opposite outcome to the competitor’s litigator.

Eben writes (and I add emphasis):
Your generation, unlike all previous generations of lawyers in New York City, will be competing for daily bread against well-trained lawyers in New Delhi and Bombay. The savagery of leverage will soon make corporate finance practice and large litigation support--in general, in fact, the back office practice on which large firms currently thrive—a practice you can't afford to be in. The legal industry is going to look in future more like the garment industry, and more so at its top than it will at its bottom. The jobs that have been considered elite for two generations, and for which your institution is best equipped to train you, are about to globalize elsewhere, leaving a steeper pyramid with much less room at the top for people like you.

The marginal return to transactional work of an investment in legal education will certainly diminish. The mandate for transactional work is not binary: it is to maximize income through contract negotiation [?]. Ivy-educated lawyers will be only slightly more valuable, and much more costly, than graduates of third-tier schools, lawyers in India, and software.

But lawmaking by litigation, unlike transactional negotiations, does not produce value that is easily measured and compared to the costs of production. It implicates the very existence of a stream of value for the indefinite future. It rallies powerful opposing interests. It is war by other means. War leads to arms races, and arms races get out of control. Corporations with immeasurably large interests in changing the law will continue to pay unconscionably large sums to control the “best” possible sources of creative legal ideas.

Law firms, congress, and law schools blaze the path of the law. But when the temptation of corporate money influences the direction they choose, it is only incidental that the partner signs our paychecks, the congressman signs the bill, and Schizer signs our diploma.

1] better is all that’s needed 2] social values are also [high value—uncomputable value? Invaluable? Priceless?]. Whether the pursuit of vast financial value or the pursuit of immeasurable social value is a stronger temptation for the lawyers, legislators, and educators who blaze the path of the law is a question ultimately in their hands.

may reduce the law firm’s comparative advantage over the law market in brokering and networking legal ideas.

Those other innovations were in distribution channels—_ _ . The lawyer’s “distribution channel” is the neurons in judges’ and jurors’ brains. Those other innovations could be objectively measured: compare _ to the market __. But every legal case is unique

Sandor: PROBLEM:Reputation / black box SOLUTIONS: break open black box How much of our profession will be “opened up” in this way?

cf. Coase: market or firm? An innovation (here, internet) doesn’t just lower cost of market—it lowers cost of firm. And so firm may become consolidated (e.g. internal Wikis ...)

>
>
In an arms race, "better than the competitor" is all that’s needed. Corporations with immeasurably large interests in changing the law will continue to pay unconscionably large sums to keep the “better” sources of creative legal ideas away from their competitors.
 
Added:
>
>
Legally educated persons have a monopoly in the production of these ideas, and law schools have a monopoly on creating legally educated persons. Columbia Law School has no incentive to educate its students for the new economy, as long as no other "top tier" law school does.
 
Added:
>
>
However, other schools will. It's what we comfortably call "second tier" schools--schools whose teachers are practitioners instead of scholars--schools that compete with each other to break their students into firms--that will produce the lawyers that will outstrip us.
 

-- AndrewGradman - 19 Jan 2008


DeathofGiantFirms 18 - 23 Jan 2008 - Main.ChristinaYoun
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"

The Death of the Giant Firm?

Line: 139 to 139
 

-- BarbPitman - 23 Jan 2008

Added:
>
>

I definitely think flexibility is a key issue for us as we enter the legal work force and I think a number of big name law firms are realizing it too. A few of the partners I met with over break from two of these big firms specifically addressed the problem of over-specialization in most big firms. One partner told me about his friend who was a specialist in one particular statute pertaining to real estate in California and was out of a job because the Californian legislature basically decided to get rid of it. Both firms recently implemented new programs to train their incoming junior associates to have a broader range of expertise even if it’s within one practice area/group.

That said, I agree with Barb that the “brokering” task of lawyers is here for the long run. A lot of information is open to the public for its use, but people lack the resources (time, money in the form of lost wages, maybe education, etc.) or maybe the patience to sift through all the information and figure things out. They can probably get the answers eventually, but as Barb said, probably not in the fashion or capacity of that of a trained attorney.

Finally, regarding Justin’s statement that “pedigree won't matter as much as what you can do for your clients,” I agree that in the end, clients really care about results. In fact, it has been that way for a long time. One can just look to the partners of big firms. Most of the partners I met with actually went to lower ranked or local schools. The way you make partner, they say, is by building your own “book” of clients. That is, you have to be business-savvy and be able to carry your clients. Nonetheless, these partners seemed to want to hire people from top law schools instead of more people with their similar educational background. (Maybe because we’re easier to program into work-machines who won’t steal their clients?) Anyway, my point was that regardless of what causes their predilections and what not, as brand new attorneys just starting off, there will be a certain market of employers who will give us jobs. Even with the fall of big firms, I cannot imagine a completely unorganized mass of single attorney offices and I cannot imagine anyone setting up shop fresh out of law school. Where will all the partners with their preferences for ivy-educated lawyers go after the fall? They will probably set up some sorts of practice groups. Someone has got to hire/work for or with others even with the fall of big firms.

-- ChristinaYoun - 23 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->

DeathofGiantFirms 17 - 23 Jan 2008 - Main.BarbPitman
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"

The Death of the Giant Firm?

Line: 133 to 133
 Even still, flexibility will remain important. If we truly are able to shape peoples thoughts, reasoning, and actions using our words then there will always be market for those of us who can do it well.

-- AdamCarlis - 23 Jan 2008

Added:
>
>

Adam, I don't want to appear to be jumping on you again, but your analysis might change if you look at the legal practice options as being broader than the ability to predict what courts will do. Most attorneys never interact with courts or court personnel and are not involved in the litigation process from any angle. Law school curriculum is focused on building analytical skills in the first year by analyzing court cases and learning the federal court process, but most attorneys never professionally steps foot in a courtroom after being "sworn in" to practice law. Many attorneys instead "broker" information and predictions with regards to governmental agencies, other private entities, the legislature, the body politic, the election process (predicting/supporting election outcomes), other law firms, defined community and private interest groups, and the press. There's just way too much information out there that is best assessed first-hand from an experientially-intuitive process and that is coming from a number of disparate places for the average person (or some overseas lawyer) to attain both the "predictability quotient" and knowledge of the law necessary to confidently assess every area in which that would-be client may have a legal or quasi-legal interest. In other words, while the type and nature of lawyering needs may change (just look at IP), the need for on-site, informed lawyers will always exist in some capacity. Consequently, in my opinion, the legal/informational "brokerage" part of lawyering will always be viable in some form in the United States. Justin's point about being flexible hits on this.

-- BarbPitman - 23 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->
\ No newline at end of file

DeathofGiantFirms 16 - 23 Jan 2008 - Main.AdamCarlis
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"

The Death of the Giant Firm?

Line: 126 to 126
 I respond to Christina by saying two things. First, I agree that there is a branding market out there, and that name of where you went to school can open doors for you, but I agree with Adam that this need not always be so. So the question then becomes, what else (besides go to a top school) can we do to to insulate ourselves in job stability and happiness? I think that Eben hit the nail on the head when he said that the key is to learn to be 'flexible' and to be able to do a variety of different things for different clients. There is a great saying that I think expresses this well: "the more you can do, the more you can do". If the 'death of firms' occurs, the pedigree won't matter as much as what you can do for your clients.

-- JustinColannino - 23 Jan 2008

Added:
>
>

I think that is pretty accurate, Justin. The only way, obviously, that is not so is if the "death of firms" actually means the death of lawyering in that individuals, armed with access to information, education, and some great computer software can do about as good as you or I when it comes to researching the law or constructing arguments. Then, instead of being the lawyers we will likely be reduced to nothing more than signatories for our client's briefs. While I don't see that happening any time soon, who can predict?

Even still, flexibility will remain important. If we truly are able to shape peoples thoughts, reasoning, and actions using our words then there will always be market for those of us who can do it well.

-- AdamCarlis - 23 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->

DeathofGiantFirms 15 - 23 Jan 2008 - Main.JustinColannino
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"

The Death of the Giant Firm?

Line: 122 to 122
 The only possible flaw in that analysis is if the same factor that destroys big firms does so by democratizing information to such an extent that developing the ability to predict what courts will do becomes attainable to the average person. Then, you wouldn't need a lawyer at all (it would be like if we developed a kangaroo-style pouch, causing the market for bags to plummet).

-- AdamCarlis - 23 Jan 2008

Added:
>
>
I respond to Christina by saying two things. First, I agree that there is a branding market out there, and that name of where you went to school can open doors for you, but I agree with Adam that this need not always be so. So the question then becomes, what else (besides go to a top school) can we do to to insulate ourselves in job stability and happiness? I think that Eben hit the nail on the head when he said that the key is to learn to be 'flexible' and to be able to do a variety of different things for different clients. There is a great saying that I think expresses this well: "the more you can do, the more you can do". If the 'death of firms' occurs, the pedigree won't matter as much as what you can do for your clients.

-- JustinColannino - 23 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->
\ No newline at end of file

DeathofGiantFirms 14 - 23 Jan 2008 - Main.AdamCarlis
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"

The Death of the Giant Firm?

Line: 117 to 117
 No matter what happens to big firms in general, it seems that there will be a market for lawyers trained a ivy and other top tiered schools. For some reason or another, society seems to place value in the so-called "pedigree" or status of a person, object, etc. Just looking at the "luxury goods" markets, why is there a market for Luis Vuitton and Chloe handbags when one can get the same bag with the same quality for about $1000 less? Why is there a market for BMW and Mercedes-Benz when one can purchase a Honda or Toyota for half the price of the former? I am not saying that everyone or even many people will opt for the more expensive option, but I do think that there will be a substantial amount of demand, at least enough demand to allow for the perpetuation of the current system in place. I think there is something to be said about the value society places on the name attached to certain institutions and the price it is willing to pay for them. Even with all the increased competition from lawyers of other countries, I feel that there will still be a market for lawyers "top tier schools."

-- ChristinaYoun - 22 Jan 2008

Added:
>
>

The only possible flaw in that analysis is if the same factor that destroys big firms does so by democratizing information to such an extent that developing the ability to predict what courts will do becomes attainable to the average person. Then, you wouldn't need a lawyer at all (it would be like if we developed a kangaroo-style pouch, causing the market for bags to plummet).

-- AdamCarlis - 23 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->

DeathofGiantFirms 13 - 22 Jan 2008 - Main.ChristinaYoun
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"

The Death of the Giant Firm?

Line: 112 to 112
 
  • Yes. I think your analysis would be right if your factual speculations were accurate. As the topic interests people, which it should, we'll talk about it in class on Wednesday.
    -- EbenMoglen - 22 Jan 2008
Added:
>
>

No matter what happens to big firms in general, it seems that there will be a market for lawyers trained a ivy and other top tiered schools. For some reason or another, society seems to place value in the so-called "pedigree" or status of a person, object, etc. Just looking at the "luxury goods" markets, why is there a market for Luis Vuitton and Chloe handbags when one can get the same bag with the same quality for about $1000 less? Why is there a market for BMW and Mercedes-Benz when one can purchase a Honda or Toyota for half the price of the former? I am not saying that everyone or even many people will opt for the more expensive option, but I do think that there will be a substantial amount of demand, at least enough demand to allow for the perpetuation of the current system in place. I think there is something to be said about the value society places on the name attached to certain institutions and the price it is willing to pay for them. Even with all the increased competition from lawyers of other countries, I feel that there will still be a market for lawyers "top tier schools."

-- ChristinaYoun - 22 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->

DeathofGiantFirms 12 - 22 Jan 2008 - Main.EbenMoglen
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
Changed:
<
<
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress)
>
>

The Death of the Giant Firm?

 Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Now that I'm going online to upload this, I just discovered i got a b minus in torts, so take my arguments with a heavy dose of skepticism.
Line: 108 to 109
 

-- SandorMarton - 22 Jan 2008

Deleted:
<
<
 
<--/commentPlugin-->
o
 \ No newline at end of file
Added:
>
>
  • Yes. I think your analysis would be right if your factual speculations were accurate. As the topic interests people, which it should, we'll talk about it in class on Wednesday.
    -- EbenMoglen - 22 Jan 2008

 
<--/commentPlugin-->

DeathofGiantFirms 11 - 22 Jan 2008 - Main.SandorMarton
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress)
Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Line: 88 to 88
 http://www.nytimes.com/2007/10/31/education/31lawschool.html?ex=1352437200&en=07e3ca16683dd3b5&ei=5124&partner=permalink&exprod=permalink

-- CarinaWallance - 22 Jan 2008

Added:
>
>

Eben,

I started to write a response, but then went to the link provided by Makalika. This quote summarizes what I wanted to say:

"Instead, offshoring is likely to hit low-level work typically performed by legal assistants, paralegals and possibly even junior lawyers who cut their teeth on rote assignments."

At big firms, I read this as doc review. With the current ABA rules in place, how would overseas firms would be able to provide the same sort of transactional and litigation services in the U.S. that U.S. firms provide without hiring American lawyers at American salaries?

Further, isn't a substantial portion of document review already outsourced to temps? Just typing "temp doc review" into google yields pages of job postings and comments about how awful the work is. My point is that since much of this work is already outsourced to graduates whose employment prospects were poor from their respective schools, how does moving it overseas negatively impact the large firms? Additionally, if the above is true, it seems like the impact will be more at the bottom than the top.

Finally, if large firms are limiting their outsourcing to doc review, how does this mean the "death" of big firms? It seems as though quite the opposite is true: big firm partners stand to greatly increase profits per partner by paying a lawyer in India $10/hour to review documents instead of hiring an American temp agency.

Is your point that, over time, more and more work will become outsourced and that eventually clients will feel comfortable having Indian lawyers conduct M&A deals (for example) from New Delhi? It seems as though the necessary radical shift in client perception as well as the difficulty in overcoming the inertia of the legal "guild" would mean that such a change would take somewhat longer than 10 years.

Thoughts?

-- SandorMarton - 22 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->
o

DeathofGiantFirms 10 - 22 Jan 2008 - Main.CarinaWallance
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress)
Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Line: 81 to 81
 If there's pre-class interest in reading more about this, I found this article after 2 seconds on Google: http://money.cnn.com/2004/10/14/news/economy/lawyer_outsourcing/?cnn=yes

-- MakalikaNaholowaa - 20 Jan 2008

Added:
>
>

Here is a link to an article about the changes in the law school curriculum that have been taking place in response to some of the issues discussed here. I am interested in hearing more from people about Columbia's position in revising the law school curriculum to address such 'world changes' as well as the effect such changes can be expected to have at a practical level.

http://www.nytimes.com/2007/10/31/education/31lawschool.html?ex=1352437200&en=07e3ca16683dd3b5&ei=5124&partner=permalink&exprod=permalink

-- CarinaWallance - 22 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->
o

DeathofGiantFirms 9 - 21 Jan 2008 - Main.AndrewGradman
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress)
Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Now that I'm going online to upload this, I just discovered i got a b minus in torts, so take my arguments with a heavy dose of skepticism.
Changed:
<
<
Eben believes that law firms will be extinct by the time we inherit them. I have my own opinions on what made giant firms so successful, and what could make them obsolete.
>
>
Eben believes that giant corporate firms will be extinct by the time we inherit them. I have wondered what could make them obsolete.
 
Changed:
<
<
The richest corporations want their legal work mass-produced and custom-fit. Big firms accommodate these clients by exploiting economies of scale. The deep bench supplies apprentices to do drudge work for their mentors, and many specialists packed under one roof cross-pollinate their ideas, as at interdisciplinary research universities or think tanks.
>
>
First, why were they successful? The richest corporations want their legal work mass-produced and custom-fit. Big firms accommodate these clients by exploiting economies of scale. The deep bench supplies apprentices to do drudge work for their mentors, and packing specialists under one roof improves the cross-pollination their ideas, as at interdisciplinary research universities or think tanks.
 
Changed:
<
<
I believe that Eben believes that the efficient trade in information will abolish the ownership of symbolic representations, materially, and then legally. Then the brokers and networkers of creative thought will become obsolete. Blogs broke the media conglomerate’s monopoly on distributing news. Recording companies will go the way of switchboard operators. Middle Management is being crushed by flattening corporate hierarchies. The continental investment banks ceded power to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies together as second semester seniors.
>
>
I believe that Eben believes that the cheap exchange of information will abolish the ownership of symbolic representations: when the “exclusive” right to use becomes unenforceable, the right itself becomes a __. . Then the brokers and networkers of creative thought will become obsolete. Blogs broke the media conglomerate’s monopoly on distributing news. Recording companies will go the way of switchboard operators. Middle Management is being crushed by flattening corporate hierarchies. The continental investment banks ceded power to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies together as second semester seniors.
 
Changed:
<
<
By gambling on their own hedge fund over a hierarchical bank, perhaps these friends were selling short our industry too. Perhaps the same centrifugal force will disintegrate giant law firms. Certainly, raw jurisprudential data will be free one day, perhaps when some Robin Hood scans in the entire written Westlaw and Nexis registers, then writes a Google-like algorithm to organize it into Wikipedia-like linked pages. Lone-practitioner Davids will keep pace with firm Goliaths by outsourcing drudgework to India or their cell phone.
>
>
But creative work will never be socialized, at least until someone invents mind-reading or artificial intelligence. Hedge fund managers will still need intuition to predict capital flow from commercial data; managers will need insight to market and innovate; reporters will always rely on pluck to formulate questions, anticipate the scene of the crime, and research non-symbolic facts; songwriters will always daydream and smoke pot.
 
Changed:
<
<
But creativity will never be socialized, at least until someone invents mind-reading or artificial intelligence. Hedge fund managers will still struggle to predict capital flow from commercial data; managers will market and innovate; blogs will rely on reporters to formulate questions, anticipate the scene of the crime, and research non-symbolic facts; good musicians will always smoke pot and drop acid.
>
>
So I must rephrase my original question: what is essential to corporate legal services, and what structure and scale will generate that most efficiently?
 
Changed:
<
<
So what is essential to legal services, and what structure and scale will generate it most efficiently?
>
>
Some legal products are not valued for being “good,” but for being “better” than the competitor’s. When the litigator’s client is committed to reaching a final verdict, or when the lobbyist or appellant proposes to reform the law for the indefinite future, his mandate is to produce a binary outcome (winning). Legally educated persons have a monopoly in the production of these decisions, because their future creative product is inalienable. The demand for a given litigator will be proportional to his or her relative ability to deny the opposite outcome to the competitor’s litigator.

Eben writes (and I add emphasis):
Your generation, unlike all previous generations of lawyers in New York City, will be competing for daily bread against well-trained lawyers in New Delhi and Bombay. The savagery of leverage will soon make corporate finance practice and large litigation support--in general, in fact, the back office practice on which large firms currently thrive—a practice you can't afford to be in. The legal industry is going to look in future more like the garment industry, and more so at its top than it will at its bottom. The jobs that have been considered elite for two generations, and for which your institution is best equipped to train you, are about to globalize elsewhere, leaving a steeper pyramid with much less room at the top for people like you.

The marginal return to transactional work of an investment in legal education will certainly diminish. The mandate for transactional work is not binary: it is to maximize income through contract negotiation [?]. Ivy-educated lawyers will be only slightly more valuable, and much more costly, than graduates of third-tier schools, lawyers in India, and software.

But lawmaking by litigation, unlike transactional negotiations, does not produce value that is easily measured and compared to the costs of production. It implicates the very existence of a stream of value for the indefinite future. It rallies powerful opposing interests. It is war by other means. War leads to arms races, and arms races get out of control. Corporations with immeasurably large interests in changing the law will continue to pay unconscionably large sums to control the “best” possible sources of creative legal ideas.

Law firms, congress, and law schools blaze the path of the law. But when the temptation of corporate money influences the direction they choose, it is only incidental that the partner signs our paychecks, the congressman signs the bill, and Schizer signs our diploma.

1] better is all that’s needed 2] social values are also [high value—uncomputable value? Invaluable? Priceless?]. Whether the pursuit of vast financial value or the pursuit of immeasurable social value is a stronger temptation for the lawyers, legislators, and educators who blaze the path of the law is a question ultimately in their hands.

 may reduce the law firm’s comparative advantage over the law market in brokering and networking legal ideas.

DeathofGiantFirms 8 - 20 Jan 2008 - Main.MakalikaNaholowaa
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress)
Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Line: 61 to 61
 
Added:
>
>

If there's pre-class interest in reading more about this, I found this article after 2 seconds on Google: http://money.cnn.com/2004/10/14/news/economy/lawyer_outsourcing/?cnn=yes

-- MakalikaNaholowaa - 20 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->
o

DeathofGiantFirms 7 - 20 Jan 2008 - Main.AndrewGradman
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
Changed:
<
<
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress) Started this on the plane to Chicago.
>
>
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress)
 Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Now that I'm going online to upload this, I just discovered i got a b minus in torts, so take my arguments with a heavy dose of skepticism.
Changed:
<
<
Eben believes that law firms will be extinct by the time we inherit them. Let’s entertain this theory. What made giant firms so successful, and what could make them obsolete? The richest corporations want their legal work mass-produced and custom-fit. Big firms accommodate these clients by exploiting economies of scale. The deep bench supplies hands to do the tedious bidding of their mentors, who shed scales of wisdom for their young apprentices to grow into. And specialists packed under one roof cross-pollinate their ideas, as at the interdisciplinary research university or think tank—only this network is proprietary, and for profit.
I believe that Eben believes that the efficient trade in symbols abolished the ownership of symbolic representations, materially if not yet legally. In that case the brokers and networkers of creative thought will become obsolete. Recording companies will go the way of switchboard operators. Blogs broke the media conglomerate’s monopoly on distributing news. Middle Management is being crushed by flattening corporate hierarchies. The continental investment banks lost mastery of the sea to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies together as second semester seniors.
The same centrifugal forces are disintegrating facets of our industry. By gambling on their own hedge fund over a hierarchical bank, perhaps these friends were selling short our giant law firms too. Certainly, raw jurisprudential data will be free one day. Some Robin Hood will scan in the entire written Westlaw and Nexis registers, then write a Google-like algorithm to organize it into Wikipedia-like linked pages. Perhaps a third-year Spartacus will expose his firm’s proprietary written memoranda, revealing by his crucifixion the wisdom of the legal elite to the lone practitioner. Davids will keep pace with Goliaths by outsourcing drudgework to India or a clever cell phone.
But creativity will never be fully socialized until someone invents mind-reading. Therefore the small chunks that break off from large corporate structures will bear their pattern. Cutting-edge hedge funds inherited the financial sector’s historic mission—predicting capital flow from commercial data. Modern management methods survive because they are the fittest way to fulfill tasks that Peter Drucker described in the ‘XXs—marketing and innovation. Blogs that spread news still rely on reporters to harvest it, by formulating questions, anticipating the scene of the crime, and researching non-symbolic facts. Better music will always be written by people who smoked pot and dropped acid.
So what is the essential legal service, and what structure and scale generates it most efficiently?
>
>
Eben believes that law firms will be extinct by the time we inherit them. I have my own opinions on what made giant firms so successful, and what could make them obsolete.

The richest corporations want their legal work mass-produced and custom-fit. Big firms accommodate these clients by exploiting economies of scale. The deep bench supplies apprentices to do drudge work for their mentors, and many specialists packed under one roof cross-pollinate their ideas, as at interdisciplinary research universities or think tanks.

I believe that Eben believes that the efficient trade in information will abolish the ownership of symbolic representations, materially, and then legally. Then the brokers and networkers of creative thought will become obsolete. Blogs broke the media conglomerate’s monopoly on distributing news. Recording companies will go the way of switchboard operators. Middle Management is being crushed by flattening corporate hierarchies. The continental investment banks ceded power to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies together as second semester seniors.

By gambling on their own hedge fund over a hierarchical bank, perhaps these friends were selling short our industry too. Perhaps the same centrifugal force will disintegrate giant law firms. Certainly, raw jurisprudential data will be free one day, perhaps when some Robin Hood scans in the entire written Westlaw and Nexis registers, then writes a Google-like algorithm to organize it into Wikipedia-like linked pages. Lone-practitioner Davids will keep pace with firm Goliaths by outsourcing drudgework to India or their cell phone.

But creativity will never be socialized, at least until someone invents mind-reading or artificial intelligence. Hedge fund managers will still struggle to predict capital flow from commercial data; managers will market and innovate; blogs will rely on reporters to formulate questions, anticipate the scene of the crime, and research non-symbolic facts; good musicians will always smoke pot and drop acid.

So what is essential to legal services, and what structure and scale will generate it most efficiently?

 may reduce the law firm’s comparative advantage over the law market in brokering and networking legal ideas.

Those other innovations were in distribution channels—_ _ . The lawyer’s “distribution channel” is the neurons in judges’ and jurors’ brains. Those other innovations could be objectively measured: compare _ to the market __. But every legal case is unique

Changed:
<
<
Sandor: PROBLEM:Reputation / black box SOLUTIONS: break open black box How much of our profession will be “opened up” in this way?
>
>
Sandor: PROBLEM:Reputation / black box SOLUTIONS: break open black box How much of our profession will be “opened up” in this way?
 cf. Coase: market or firm? An innovation (here, internet) doesn’t just lower cost of market—it lowers cost of firm. And so firm may become consolidated (e.g. internal Wikis ...)
Line: 56 to 61
 
Deleted:
<
<
 
<--/commentPlugin-->
 \ No newline at end of file
Added:
>
>
 
<--/commentPlugin-->
o

DeathofGiantFirms 6 - 20 Jan 2008 - Main.EbenMoglen
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress) Started this on the plane to Chicago.
Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Line: 33 to 33
 Back to the original question Andrew posed: I'm not entirely sure why we should expect the death of the law firm anytime soon, either. Anyone have ideas about why Eben said this? Or your own thoughts on the matter?

-- KateVershov - 19 Jan 2008

Added:
>
>

I'll explain in more detail what I actually meant, which isn't what Andrew assumed, next Wednesday. For the moment, let me just restate it, which may help: Your generation, unlike all previous generations of lawyers in New York City, will be competing for daily bread against well-trained lawyers in New Delhi and Bombay. The savagery of leverage will soon make corporate finance practice and large litigation support--in general, in fact, the back office practice on which large firms currently thrive--a practice you can't afford to be in. The legal industry is going to look in future more like the garment industry, and more so at its top than it will at its bottom. The jobs that have been considered elite for two generations, and for which your institution is best equipped to train you, are about to globalize elsewhere, leaving a steeper pyramid with much less room at the top for people like you.

-- EbenMoglen - 19 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->

DeathofGiantFirms 5 - 20 Jan 2008 - Main.AndrewGradman
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress) Started this on the plane to Chicago.
Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Now that I'm going online to upload this, I just discovered i got a b minus in torts, so take my arguments with a heavy dose of skepticism.
Changed:
<
<
Eben believes that law firms will be extinct by the time we look to inherit them. I’ll entertain his theory. What made giant firms so successful, and what is making them obsolete? The richest corporations want their legal work mass-produced and custom-fit. Larger firms grab richer clients by exploiting economies of scale. The vertical deep bench supplies young apprentices to do the tedious bidding of their mentors, who shed scales of wisdom for them to grow into. And horizontal cross-pollination stimulates creativity, so giant law firms pack specialists under one roof, like the interdisciplinary research university or think tank —only this network is proprietary, and for profit. The centrifugal force of cheap information lowers the cost of brokering and networking creativity. Music brokerages (recording companies) are as obsolete as telephone switchboard operators. Corporate management hierarchies have flattened, crushing out the “switchboard operators” in Middle Management. Blogs broke the newspapers’ monopoly on distributing news. The continental investment banks lost mastery of the sea to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies as second semester seniors. When these friends opened their hedge fund, they sold short the giant law firm's long-term prospects.
>
>
Eben believes that law firms will be extinct by the time we inherit them. Let’s entertain this theory. What made giant firms so successful, and what could make them obsolete? The richest corporations want their legal work mass-produced and custom-fit. Big firms accommodate these clients by exploiting economies of scale. The deep bench supplies hands to do the tedious bidding of their mentors, who shed scales of wisdom for their young apprentices to grow into. And specialists packed under one roof cross-pollinate their ideas, as at the interdisciplinary research university or think tank—only this network is proprietary, and for profit.
I believe that Eben believes that the efficient trade in symbols abolished the ownership of symbolic representations, materially if not yet legally. In that case the brokers and networkers of creative thought will become obsolete. Recording companies will go the way of switchboard operators. Blogs broke the media conglomerate’s monopoly on distributing news. Middle Management is being crushed by flattening corporate hierarchies. The continental investment banks lost mastery of the sea to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies together as second semester seniors.
The same centrifugal forces are disintegrating facets of our industry. By gambling on their own hedge fund over a hierarchical bank, perhaps these friends were selling short our giant law firms too. Certainly, raw jurisprudential data will be free one day. Some Robin Hood will scan in the entire written Westlaw and Nexis registers, then write a Google-like algorithm to organize it into Wikipedia-like linked pages. Perhaps a third-year Spartacus will expose his firm’s proprietary written memoranda, revealing by his crucifixion the wisdom of the legal elite to the lone practitioner. Davids will keep pace with Goliaths by outsourcing drudgework to India or a clever cell phone.
But creativity will never be fully socialized until someone invents mind-reading. Therefore the small chunks that break off from large corporate structures will bear their pattern. Cutting-edge hedge funds inherited the financial sector’s historic mission—predicting capital flow from commercial data. Modern management methods survive because they are the fittest way to fulfill tasks that Peter Drucker described in the ‘XXs—marketing and innovation. Blogs that spread news still rely on reporters to harvest it, by formulating questions, anticipating the scene of the crime, and researching non-symbolic facts. Better music will always be written by people who smoked pot and dropped acid.
So what is the essential legal service, and what structure and scale generates it most efficiently? may reduce the law firm’s comparative advantage over the law market in brokering and networking legal ideas.
 
Changed:
<
<
with these trends in mind. But aren’t we lawyers special? Those other innovations were in distribution channels—_ _ . The lawyer’s “distribution channel” is the neurons in judges’ and jurors’ brains. Those other innovations could be objectively measured: compare _ to the market __. But every legal case is unique

Sandor: PROBLEM:Reputation / black box SOLUTIONS: break open black box Justin Colannino—Competitors to Westlaw and Nexis will be cheaper and searcheable like google and wikipedia Scan it in, automate the piracy

>
>
Those other innovations were in distribution channels—_ _ . The lawyer’s “distribution channel” is the neurons in judges’ and jurors’ brains. Those other innovations could be objectively measured: compare _ to the market __. But every legal case is unique
 
Added:
>
>
Sandor: PROBLEM:Reputation / black box SOLUTIONS: break open black box
 How much of our profession will be “opened up” in this way?

cf. Coase: market or firm? An innovation (here, internet) doesn’t just lower cost of market—it lowers cost of firm. And so firm may become consolidated (e.g. internal Wikis ...)


DeathofGiantFirms 4 - 19 Jan 2008 - Main.KateVershov
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress) Started this on the plane to Chicago.
Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Line: 26 to 26
 I'm not awake enough to address the main question, but I just want to note that Wexis may not disappear as much as add value to hang on--for example, headnotes, the key number index, and so on. The core of the judicial opinions--public domain--is increasingly available free on court websites and on Columbia's own altlaw.org, but until someone starts writing public domain headnotes and indices (or until someone develops a MUCH smarter search for law), Wexis will be here to stay (without even mentioning all the secondary sources that will need to be freed or still bought and made available in print). Anyway, until someone starts writing these for free, competitors will need to pay someone to write their own or pay West etc. and keep feeding them.

-- DanielHarris - 19 Jan 2008

Added:
>
>

Back to the original question Andrew posed: I'm not entirely sure why we should expect the death of the law firm anytime soon, either. Anyone have ideas about why Eben said this? Or your own thoughts on the matter?

-- KateVershov - 19 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->

DeathofGiantFirms 3 - 19 Jan 2008 - Main.AndrewGradman
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
Changed:
<
<
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress) Started this on the plane to Chicago. Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I can’t forget to credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for arguing that Westlaw and Nexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias. Now that I'm going online to upload it, I just discovered i got a b minus in torts, so don't take any of my arguments too seriously.
>
>
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress) Started this on the plane to Chicago.
Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I must credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for predicting that Wexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias.
Now that I'm going online to upload this, I just discovered i got a b minus in torts, so take my arguments with a heavy dose of skepticism.
 Eben believes that law firms will be extinct by the time we look to inherit them. I’ll entertain his theory. What made giant firms so successful, and what is making them obsolete? The richest corporations want their legal work mass-produced and custom-fit. Larger firms grab richer clients by exploiting economies of scale. The vertical deep bench supplies young apprentices to do the tedious bidding of their mentors, who shed scales of wisdom for them to grow into. And horizontal cross-pollination stimulates creativity, so giant law firms pack specialists under one roof, like the interdisciplinary research university or think tank —only this network is proprietary, and for profit.
Changed:
<
<
The centrifugal force of cheap information has been disaggregating other knowledge industries. Cheap information cut the costs of creativity in objective ways: Music brokerages (recording companies) are as obsolete as telephone switchboard operators. Corporate management hierarchies flattened, crushing out the “switchboard operators” in Middle Management. Blogs broke the newspapers’ monopoly on distributing news. The investment banking continents lost mastery of the sea to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies as bored second semester seniors. When these friends chose to open their own hedge fund, they were selling short the long-term prospects of the giant law firm. with these trends in mind. But aren’t we lawyers special? continent Those other innovations were in distribution channels—_ _ . The lawyer’s “distribution channel” is the neurons in judges’ and jurors’ brains. Those other innovations could be objectively measured: compare _ to the market __. But every legal case is unique

Sandor: PROBLEM:Reputation / black box SOLUTIONS: break open black box Justin Colannino—Competitors to Westlaw and Nexis will be cheaper and searcheable like google and wikipedia Scan it in, automate the piracy

>
>
The centrifugal force of cheap information lowers the cost of brokering and networking creativity. Music brokerages (recording companies) are as obsolete as telephone switchboard operators. Corporate management hierarchies have flattened, crushing out the “switchboard operators” in Middle Management. Blogs broke the newspapers’ monopoly on distributing news. The continental investment banks lost mastery of the sea to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies as second semester seniors. When these friends opened their hedge fund, they sold short the giant law firm's long-term prospects.

with these trends in mind. But aren’t we lawyers special? Those other innovations were in distribution channels—_ _ . The lawyer’s “distribution channel” is the neurons in judges’ and jurors’ brains. Those other innovations could be objectively measured: compare _ to the market __. But every legal case is unique

Sandor: PROBLEM:Reputation / black box SOLUTIONS: break open black box Justin Colannino—Competitors to Westlaw and Nexis will be cheaper and searcheable like google and wikipedia Scan it in, automate the piracy

 How much of our profession will be “opened up” in this way?

cf. Coase: market or firm? An innovation (here, internet) doesn’t just lower cost of market—it lowers cost of firm. And so firm may become consolidated (e.g. internal Wikis ...)

Deleted:
<
<
f
 

-- AndrewGradman - 19 Jan 2008


DeathofGiantFirms 2 - 19 Jan 2008 - Main.DanielHarris
Line: 1 to 1
 
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress) Started this on the plane to Chicago.
Line: 28 to 28
 -- AndrewGradman - 19 Jan 2008
Added:
>
>

I'm not awake enough to address the main question, but I just want to note that Wexis may not disappear as much as add value to hang on--for example, headnotes, the key number index, and so on. The core of the judicial opinions--public domain--is increasingly available free on court websites and on Columbia's own altlaw.org, but until someone starts writing public domain headnotes and indices (or until someone develops a MUCH smarter search for law), Wexis will be here to stay (without even mentioning all the secondary sources that will need to be freed or still bought and made available in print). Anyway, until someone starts writing these for free, competitors will need to pay someone to write their own or pay West etc. and keep feeding them.

-- DanielHarris - 19 Jan 2008

 
 
<--/commentPlugin-->
\ No newline at end of file

DeathofGiantFirms 1 - 19 Jan 2008 - Main.AndrewGradman
Line: 1 to 1
Added:
>
>
META TOPICPARENT name="ClassNotes16Jan08"
the death of the giant firm? (Work in progress) Started this on the plane to Chicago. Since our grade is partly based on whether we’re ethical, I can’t forget to credit Sandor for arguing that the legal product includes trust, and Justin Colannino for arguing that Westlaw and Nexis will be assimilated into Googles and Wikipedias. Now that I'm going online to upload it, I just discovered i got a b minus in torts, so don't take any of my arguments too seriously.

Eben believes that law firms will be extinct by the time we look to inherit them. I’ll entertain his theory. What made giant firms so successful, and what is making them obsolete? The richest corporations want their legal work mass-produced and custom-fit. Larger firms grab richer clients by exploiting economies of scale. The vertical deep bench supplies young apprentices to do the tedious bidding of their mentors, who shed scales of wisdom for them to grow into. And horizontal cross-pollination stimulates creativity, so giant law firms pack specialists under one roof, like the interdisciplinary research university or think tank —only this network is proprietary, and for profit. The centrifugal force of cheap information has been disaggregating other knowledge industries. Cheap information cut the costs of creativity in objective ways: Music brokerages (recording companies) are as obsolete as telephone switchboard operators. Corporate management hierarchies flattened, crushing out the “switchboard operators” in Middle Management. Blogs broke the newspapers’ monopoly on distributing news. The investment banking continents lost mastery of the sea to an archipelago of hedge funds, run by irreverent geniuses like my three college classmates who started trading currencies as bored second semester seniors. When these friends chose to open their own hedge fund, they were selling short the long-term prospects of the giant law firm. with these trends in mind. But aren’t we lawyers special? continent Those other innovations were in distribution channels—_ _ . The lawyer’s “distribution channel” is the neurons in judges’ and jurors’ brains. Those other innovations could be objectively measured: compare _ to the market __. But every legal case is unique

Sandor: PROBLEM:Reputation / black box SOLUTIONS: break open black box Justin Colannino—Competitors to Westlaw and Nexis will be cheaper and searcheable like google and wikipedia Scan it in, automate the piracy

How much of our profession will be “opened up” in this way?

cf. Coase: market or firm? An innovation (here, internet) doesn’t just lower cost of market—it lowers cost of firm. And so firm may become consolidated (e.g. internal Wikis ...)

f

-- AndrewGradman - 19 Jan 2008

 
<--/commentPlugin-->

Revision 23r23 - 11 Jan 2010 - 16:52:50 - IanSullivan
Revision 22r22 - 27 Jan 2008 - 23:39:25 - AndrewGradman
Revision 21r21 - 27 Jan 2008 - 01:52:39 - AndrewGradman
Revision 20r20 - 27 Jan 2008 - 00:25:10 - AndrewGradman
Revision 19r19 - 26 Jan 2008 - 23:01:59 - AndrewGradman
Revision 18r18 - 23 Jan 2008 - 22:50:18 - ChristinaYoun
Revision 17r17 - 23 Jan 2008 - 16:30:46 - BarbPitman
Revision 16r16 - 23 Jan 2008 - 15:17:17 - AdamCarlis
Revision 15r15 - 23 Jan 2008 - 13:46:19 - JustinColannino
Revision 14r14 - 23 Jan 2008 - 12:59:19 - AdamCarlis
Revision 13r13 - 22 Jan 2008 - 18:53:03 - ChristinaYoun
Revision 12r12 - 22 Jan 2008 - 17:26:02 - EbenMoglen
Revision 11r11 - 22 Jan 2008 - 15:11:56 - SandorMarton
Revision 10r10 - 22 Jan 2008 - 03:48:29 - CarinaWallance
Revision 9r9 - 21 Jan 2008 - 05:40:10 - AndrewGradman
Revision 8r8 - 20 Jan 2008 - 06:44:21 - MakalikaNaholowaa
Revision 7r7 - 20 Jan 2008 - 06:29:03 - AndrewGradman
Revision 6r6 - 20 Jan 2008 - 01:26:42 - EbenMoglen
Revision 5r5 - 20 Jan 2008 - 00:21:44 - AndrewGradman
Revision 4r4 - 19 Jan 2008 - 21:49:43 - KateVershov
Revision 3r3 - 19 Jan 2008 - 20:16:39 - AndrewGradman
Revision 2r2 - 19 Jan 2008 - 16:32:56 - DanielHarris
Revision 1r1 - 19 Jan 2008 - 16:09:13 - AndrewGradman
This site is powered by the TWiki collaboration platform.
All material on this collaboration platform is the property of the contributing authors.
All material marked as authored by Eben Moglen is available under the license terms CC-BY-SA version 4.
Syndicate this site RSSATOM