ScottYakaitisFirstPaper 2 - 11 Oct 2014 - Main.EbenMoglen
|
|
META TOPICPARENT | name="WebPreferences" |
-- ScottYakaitis - 02 Oct 2014 | |
< < | Terrence Maxwell builds an interesting model trying to decipher the possible impact of various policy decisions in relation to literature and copyright (http://firstmonday.org/ojs/index.php/fm/article/view/1175/1095). Maxwell analyzes past decisions as a way to help analyze how decisions would effect the world going into 2100. He looks at 5 possible policy scenarios: strong copyright control, balancing public domain with author's rights, limit of public education due to lack of pop. Growth and upper limits of literacy, improve access by improving education, and retail price controls. | > > | Terrence Maxwell builds an interesting model
trying to decipher the possible impact of various policy decisions in relation to literature and copyright. Maxwell analyzes past decisions as a way to help analyze how decisions would effect the world
going into 2100. He looks at 5 possible policy scenarios: strong copyright control, balancing public domain with author's rights, limit of public education due to lack of pop. Growth and upper limits of literacy, improve access by improving education, and retail price controls. | | | |
< < | In the essay, Maxwell argues that to create both the most number of authors and the greatest profits for authors, investments should be made not into copyright but into education. The greater the world literacy, he argues, the more people will spend on reading. Not surprising. However, he found that most of the other policy considerations didn't create much in the way of different results. The only major difference, it seems, is that the number of authors in a strong copyright regime (~500k) was much higher than that of any other (~250k), with the exception of the improved education policy decision(~1000k) and controlling retail price (~400k). This suggests that the argument that copyright actually is an effective incentive for authors to create does a least have some backbone to it. While, it is perhaps not an ideal world (the improved education for all seems to be) if we take the prospect of having more creators than not as a good, copyright seems to be effective. | > > |
I made the link a link for you. If you're writing on the Web, use the Web. The editor has those little link icons up there on the toolbar if you really need them, but writing the markdown of the link is faster. Push the Raw button to see the page source and learn....
This is loose blowzy writing at the beginning, where you need to be
especially clear and crisp to interest the reader. He builds an
interesting model by analyzing the past as a way of helping to
speculate about the future? He looks at five possible policy scenarios?
Good legal writing, as opposed to what lawyers write, is clear,
forceful, and economical. At their very best, tomes affect the
world slowly. A lawyer's job is to get results now. In my 1L
classroom, lawyering is defined as "making things happen in society
using words." The people who comprise the social processes you are
trying to affect are busy. If their minds aren't alert when you get
to them, you need to wake them up in a fashion they find pleasant
rather than offputting. You need to be energetic, interesting, and
clear. You want them to feel that they are smarter when they read
you. This paragraph is not showing how.
In the essay, Maxwell argues that to create both the most number of authors and the greatest profits for authors, investments should be made not into copyright but into education.
Try improving this preceding sentence. Instead of 30 words, say it
in 20. Then make it the second sentence in the paragraph, where the
first is a topic sentence whose idea is yours. Link that back to
the topic of the first paragraph, the lead of the essay, where your
big idea is put forward and Maxwell is adopted as the interlocutor
for you, not the subject of your book review. It will help to have
an outline. Nothing short should ever be written without one.
The greater the world literacy, he argues, the more people will spend on reading. Not surprising. However, he found that most of the other policy considerations didn't create much in the way of different results. The only major difference, it seems, is that the number of authors in a strong copyright regime (~500k) was much higher than that of any other (~250k), with the exception of the improved education policy decision(~1000k) and controlling retail price (~400k). This suggests that the argument that copyright actually is an effective incentive for authors to create does a least have some backbone to it.
Why do made up numbers based on a model of the human future that
includes no variables other than the ones the author is pretending
to investigate "suggest" anything? That's just the fallacy of
mensuration in rhetorical blossom: if you can give a number, that
"suggests" correctness. I believe some comedian somewhere has
referred to this as "truthiness." I am in total sympathy with Mr
Maxwell's aims, I agree with the argument he is presenting, and even
I cannot find a single reason to believe what he is saying based on
this bullshit. Why do you?
While, it is perhaps not an ideal world (the improved education for all seems to be) if we take the prospect of having more creators than not as a good, copyright seems to be effective. | |
However, Maxwell concedes that he only focuses on a very limited set of variables and a variety of hidden costs may exist that he didn't take into account. When extrapolating into the future a whole variety of unforeseen or foreseen (but to complex to include in a model) scenarios can crop up. The article Four Futures by Peter Frase (https://www.jacobinmag.com/2011/12/four-futures/) attempts to hypothesize what the economies in the futures will look like. Frase argues that as time moves forward the need for human labor will decrease. Technologies such as three dimensional printing, general automation, and the internet will decrease the marginal cost of nearly everything to zero. For example, say you didn't own an umbrella and it was raining outside. Today, you could step outside and see a swarm of ad hoc merchants selling umbrellas at higher prices. In this future, you could load generic material into a three dimensional printer, find a schematic and then print the umbrella. Entire sectors of the economy would be wiped out. Manufacturing and sales would be nearly things of the past. At this point, the only major limiting cost would be the scarcity and cost of the raw materials itself. Whether or not that cost would be high or low determines which one of Frase's four futures you'll end up in. Let's focus on the future where the cost is low. | |
Could a significantly reduced copyright be an effective middle ground? If a society gave copyright protection for only one year with significant fair use exemptions to the copyright, this could perhaps deal with both problems. The small period of monopoly would still give creators an extra incentive to create. They would still be societies elite (but all societies will have an elite). However, would this might not create the same entrenched power structure. Especially if, the protection was extremely limited. One couldn't directly copy a schematic. But any small change would grant a new copyright. In addition, if the original creator of a schematic couldn't keep the underlying code secret, any enterprising creator could update and modify the original schematic. This would give just enough copy protection that if a very particular good is popular the creator is rewarded, while also keeping the copyright loose enough to allow creation and innovation. | |
> > |
Are we seriously to believe that the future of the global
political economy can be used as the pivot of an argument
about copyright policy? That's surely an example of using the
megatherium to wag the tail of a neighboring dog. What will
happen to the welfare of the human race over the next several
generations, including the global level of aggregate
employment, has surely to do also with a few uncorrelated
additional elements. This is the sort of drawing completely
out of perspective that afflicts "policy" discussion in
lobbyland. Everyone has some plausible soundbite. Smart is
knowing why all of it is nonsense.
One can say with all the authority of microeconomics that if
you lower the price of knowledge more people will acquire it.
One can say with the authority of reportage that most of the
world's children are too poor to acquire learning, and also
that when offered it, immensely bright and talented people are
liberated from hopelessness and oppression. One can therefore
say without all this pseudo-modeling that if the rules against
sharing were destroyed, tens of millions of highly gifted
individuals would begin affecting the destiny of humankind,
and hundreds of millions more would be afforded basic human
social justice by being liberated from hopelessness and
oppression. If that takes 108 words, what have you to say in
another 892, with or without Maxwell, that amplifies, reduces,
contradicts or transforms that proposition?
|
|
ScottYakaitisFirstPaper 1 - 02 Oct 2014 - Main.ScottYakaitis
|
|
> > |
META TOPICPARENT | name="WebPreferences" |
-- ScottYakaitis - 02 Oct 2014
Terrence Maxwell builds an interesting model trying to decipher the possible impact of various policy decisions in relation to literature and copyright (http://firstmonday.org/ojs/index.php/fm/article/view/1175/1095). Maxwell analyzes past decisions as a way to help analyze how decisions would effect the world going into 2100. He looks at 5 possible policy scenarios: strong copyright control, balancing public domain with author's rights, limit of public education due to lack of pop. Growth and upper limits of literacy, improve access by improving education, and retail price controls.
In the essay, Maxwell argues that to create both the most number of authors and the greatest profits for authors, investments should be made not into copyright but into education. The greater the world literacy, he argues, the more people will spend on reading. Not surprising. However, he found that most of the other policy considerations didn't create much in the way of different results. The only major difference, it seems, is that the number of authors in a strong copyright regime (~500k) was much higher than that of any other (~250k), with the exception of the improved education policy decision(~1000k) and controlling retail price (~400k). This suggests that the argument that copyright actually is an effective incentive for authors to create does a least have some backbone to it. While, it is perhaps not an ideal world (the improved education for all seems to be) if we take the prospect of having more creators than not as a good, copyright seems to be effective.
However, Maxwell concedes that he only focuses on a very limited set of variables and a variety of hidden costs may exist that he didn't take into account. When extrapolating into the future a whole variety of unforeseen or foreseen (but to complex to include in a model) scenarios can crop up. The article Four Futures by Peter Frase (https://www.jacobinmag.com/2011/12/four-futures/) attempts to hypothesize what the economies in the futures will look like. Frase argues that as time moves forward the need for human labor will decrease. Technologies such as three dimensional printing, general automation, and the internet will decrease the marginal cost of nearly everything to zero. For example, say you didn't own an umbrella and it was raining outside. Today, you could step outside and see a swarm of ad hoc merchants selling umbrellas at higher prices. In this future, you could load generic material into a three dimensional printer, find a schematic and then print the umbrella. Entire sectors of the economy would be wiped out. Manufacturing and sales would be nearly things of the past. At this point, the only major limiting cost would be the scarcity and cost of the raw materials itself. Whether or not that cost would be high or low determines which one of Frase's four futures you'll end up in. Let's focus on the future where the cost is low.
In that future, there would be very few jobs. The only major industries would be the one that produces the generic raw material for 3-d printing and the industry that is set up to design the schematics for those who will use the 3-d printers. In a strong copyright regime, those who write the code for those schematics could effectively have copyrights over extremely fundamental goods. Hypothetically speaking the program design for producing something as basic as a metal pot might be controlled (and thus monopolized). This future, Frase refers to as that of Rentism. Because of the very few still viable industries, this future could lead to a very small and very powerful elite. Since all commerce would be focused on selling particular schematics for the printers those that controlled a substantial amount of those copyrights would be wildly wealthy. This society would then suffer from a variety of the problems that a society of extreme disparity suffer.
As things are today, companies can and do copyright schematics for 3-d printers. But we have two competing interests for society. On one hand, copyright protections do seem to induce more people to enter a particular creative field. And having more people produce these sorts of schematics would be very useful for society. On the other hand, allowing strong copyright protection could potential create one of Frase's dystopian futures.
Could a significantly reduced copyright be an effective middle ground? If a society gave copyright protection for only one year with significant fair use exemptions to the copyright, this could perhaps deal with both problems. The small period of monopoly would still give creators an extra incentive to create. They would still be societies elite (but all societies will have an elite). However, would this might not create the same entrenched power structure. Especially if, the protection was extremely limited. One couldn't directly copy a schematic. But any small change would grant a new copyright. In addition, if the original creator of a schematic couldn't keep the underlying code secret, any enterprising creator could update and modify the original schematic. This would give just enough copy protection that if a very particular good is popular the creator is rewarded, while also keeping the copyright loose enough to allow creation and innovation. |
|
|
|
This site is powered by the TWiki collaboration platform. All material on this collaboration platform is the property of the contributing authors. All material marked as authored by Eben Moglen is available under the license terms CC-BY-SA version 4.
|
|