Law in the Internet Society
Ready for second review.

Making Money When Its All Free

-- By AlexeySokolin - 17 Oct 2011

Transitional Stages Matter

On the horizon is a world where cultural goods are distributed freely and quickly to everyone who wants them. Such a world fundamentally challenges the conception of private property in ideas and the businesses built on that foundation.

Now is a time of transition. Transitional stages are important because define how power is distributed and the principles that will drive cultural norms. It matters how we move from intellectual property regimes of today and how we restructure our industry. This paper explores various economic models which have emerged to address the needs of tomorrow.

Economic Axioms for Digital Goods

Digital goods such as software, music, video and text have a Marginal Cost of zero. It costs nothing to duplicate and transfer an mp3 or ebook file.

They are also called pubic goods and are nonrival, non-excludable, and subject to free ridership. While some may indeed be emergent (e.g., music, literature), many require significant capital investment. In other words, they have a non-zero Fixed Cost. Western economic theory suggests that because public goods are free to consume, they do not get produced at adequate quantity or quality without substantial subsidy. Free software may suggest otherwise.

Examples of digital with high fixed costs goods are blockbuster movies (Harry Potter), high-end video games (Starcraft), and professional software (Adobe Photoshop). These goods cost nothing to share, but large sums of money to create, requiring employees, office buildings and financing.

One of these is not like the others. As you were just pointing out, we can make free software without those inputs. Your category of "professional software" includes an image processing program, but not operating systems, databases, and office suites? Even about Photoshop you are talking through your hat. Evidently you have never encountered the GIMP.

This also includes the cost of financing which is a function of the risk of the venture. Higher-risk ventures require a higher rate of return as part of the fixed cost—start-ups and movies are expensive to finance.

That depends. All this really turns out to mean is that expensive things are expensive, and that money is sometimes expensive too. But, for example, extraordinary films are made all the time on budgets that are infinitesimal by Hollywood (or even Bollywood) standards. Expensive celebrity "actors," expensive promotion and expensive distribution (financed of course by purchases of expensive money multiplied by risk premium) are irrelevant to the production of compelling, informative, elegant and intelligent culture. So all this supposed economic sophistication is, to put it mildly, actually beside the point, as it is when the pharmaceutical industry talks about the cost of drugs.

A Survey of Business Models

Pay for Product. In the most conventional business model, people pay directly for the product or service they consume. The product has value, and the buyer is willing to pay up to their personal assessment of that value. The parties split that value assessment such that the buyer is better off and the seller is better off, subject to bargaining power (e.g., monopoly). Ethical concerns arise when the seller uses coercive political force to appropriate most of the value to itself, as in the case of Telecoms overcharging consumers to use free-to-produce text messages. Prior to the digital economy, large firm organizational structures were needed to build distribution infrastructure and spread out costs through economies of scale. Pricing power followed. In the digital economy, goods are free to distribute and the asymmetric capture of rents by oligopolies becomes difficult to justify. Even more controversial is the distributive result: those unable to pay rents are deprived of access to public resources.

Sharing. The free economy shifts the balance of power to consumers, providing on demand access to any digital good. For some, however, sharing raises ethical questions about misappropriation from other consumers. A classic free riding problem can occur, such that one group of people benefit from the contribution of another group of people (producers, sellers, or the buyers which pay and subsidize fixed costs) without their consent.

No. You're not describing the sharing economy, you're repeating bilge washed into your brain by the "content" oligopoly. In the sharing economy, producers and distributors have consented to the terms of sharing. They make production and distribution possible that otherwise would not occur, they give everyone value, and everyone has agreed to share. All the supposed problems, including the "ethical" problem you arrogantly claim we have, are therefore non-existent. I explained all this more than a decade ago in Anarchism Triumphant. Creative Commons, Free Software, the Wikipedia, and many other pillars of the sharing economy have arisen since, as I said they would. You're welcome to disagree about how all this plays out, but you're not welcome to distort the argument by assuming falsehoods.

For institutions structured to produce costly digital goods, this interferes with generating market compensation and leads to antagonism with a powerful and otherwise beneficial distribution channel. More people see the content but less profit is made.

Not necessarily. And at any rate that tradeoff is radically reductive. Is your view of the overall significance of the total replacement of the world's proprietary encyclopedias by Wikipedia, for example, captured in the proposition that "more people see the content but less profit is made"? Should we include in the cost-benefit analysis that we all have instantaneous access everywhere to information in a fashion that has changed everyone's life for the better? That we have democratized the production of knowledge in ways that will continue to transform the nature of human thought? That we have provided an experience of intense beneficial collaboration to hundreds of thousands of people around the world? Less profit? Even if that is true, who gives a shit? Economic rent is tolerable because necessary. Since when has it become an end in itself?

Freemium. Services can be tiered: one group of people uses a free product, while another pays for additional functionality. Examples include Flickr, and Dropbox. Usually the free product is targeted for personal use and the premium product is for professional use. This model is ethically attractive: all groups understand how revenue is being generated and opt-in to the system. The difficulty is reaching appropriate scale and getting enough free users to convert to premium such that the entire venture is funded.

No, the difficulty is that the need to cripple the technology in order to support the service-restriction model distorts the technology. Flickr is not better than federated photo sharing through this thing we invented about 7,000 days ago called the World Wide Web. Dropbox is a ridiculous form of stupidity-reinforced privacy-destroying cloud storage than which all Columbia students already have better alternatives available for free that no one tells them about. There's no ethical attraction in making technology deliberately worse so that you can also sell people something they don't need at prices they shouldn't have to pay. Your analysis is only attractive if you're prepared to ignore everything that someone who disagrees with you might say about it.

Advertising and Data. Instead of making money from a product directly, businesses can generate large user-bases and sell their audience. For example, 96% of Google’s revenues are from advertising. Attention is scarce and valuable to companies that sell products for which people pay directly. An alternate spin on this is to sell the underlying behavioral data of the user-base. The data provides insight on what happens next and how to best market to this population. While ingenious, these two approaches can erode the user experience, as well as their secrecy, anonymity and autonomy.

Differentiated Marketing. Another way to escape zero pricing is to market a product so that it is not a commodity, and commands a premium. Technology commentators advocate connecting with fans and generating a reason to buy with value separate from that of the free product, such as a superior experience or emotional connection. While functionalists tend to dismiss branding as brainwashing, some believe that well-marketed products create legitimate emotional benefits. The pricing can be done either by tiering, or using auctions. In the auction set-up, people self-discriminate and bid up to their willingness to pay. For some this is zero, for others it is a positive value. Successful examples are Radiohead’s “In Rainbows” (1.2 million downloads), Nine Inch Nails ($1.6 million in one week), and Kickstarter ($75 million raised). Inherent in the auction model is a utility so positive that people pay as expression of gratitude. The creator must be particularly good at signaling the differentiation of the good from a commodity such that price does not equal marginal cost.

Adjacent Product Bundling. A version of freemium and marketing, some businesses give away their core product using the distribution mechanism of sharing and make money but selling related services. A popular musician can bundle t-shirts with their music, an artist can sign limited edition prints of their digital drawings, an expert blogger can do speaking engagements on top of her regular content.

How Do We Decide

Structuring the digital economy raises a host of ethical considerations. Are we achieving the right distributive result? Are we coercing one set of people to benefit another without consent? Are our core privacy principles being undermined? Business models adapt to the philosophies we choose. We must do so carefully in this transition.

This conclusion doesn't mean anything.

We're a little better off than we were in the last draft, but some significant problems remain. Your supposed ethical objections to sharing depend on outrageous factual falsehoods uncritically repeated. Your analysis of the "profit economics" of culture contains both some factual inaccuracies and some serious theoretical blind spots. The theme of the essay now sometimes seems to be that the future should be postponed if possible, for reasons that aren't very clear except that profit in the hands of a few is inherently good and the betterment of humanity is not enough of a reason to reduce it. The primary argument on the other side—that knowledge has always been strictly rationed in human society, unjustly, but necessarily, for reasons we can now avoid, thus allowing billions of existing human beings to escape ignorance—is not even acknowledged, let alone answered.






# * Set ALLOWTOPICVIEW = TWikiAdminGroup, AlexeySokolin

Note: TWiki has strict formatting rules. Make sure you preserve the three spaces, asterisk, and extra space at the beginning of that line. If you wish to give access to any other users simply add them to the comma separated list

Navigation

Webs Webs

r10 - 14 Jan 2012 - 18:59:04 - EbenMoglen
This site is powered by the TWiki collaboration platform.
All material on this collaboration platform is the property of the contributing authors.
All material marked as authored by Eben Moglen is available under the license terms CC-BY-SA version 4.
Syndicate this site RSSATOM